FIFTH REGULATORY COLLOQUIUM - EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Footnotes

  1. Formally known as the Final Act Embodying the Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations, 15 April 1994.
  2. And also telecommunications policies adopted at the regional, supra-national level by the European Union.
  3. Members of the WTO are governments, but not necessarily governments of independent states. It is also important to note that in practice the European Commission represents, and negotiates in the WTO, for the 15 member states of the European Union.
  4. In all four modes, the following definitions apply:
  5. "Market access" refers to a member's optional commitments to open any of its market sectors to the supply of service (in any of the four "modes" of supply) by service suppliers of other members.
  6. "National treatment" refers to a member's optional commitment to treat service suppliers and services of any other Member no less favourably than it treats its "own like" services and service suppliers.
  7. Technically, the entries in the Schedule (other than the "additional commitments" discussed in Part III of this summary) state the limitations on market access and national treatment that remain in force once the member's commitments have been implemented.
  8. A more technical and detailed discussion of the GATS obligations is provided, with extensive references to the text of the Agreement, in Chapter 3.
  9. Annex on Negotiations on Basic Telecommunications (Legal Texts, p. 364).
  10. New Zealand is a notable exception.
  11. Accounting rates are the rates of payment used when a telecommunications carrier compensates a carrier in another country for carrying traffic to a destination in that country. The accounting rate system is described in Briefing Report No. 3 in this series, Michael Tyler, Global Mobile Personal Communications Systems (Geneva, ITU, March 1995), pp. 51ff.
  12. The notable exception being the emergence in recent years of common telecommunication legislation within the European Union.
  13. Each member undertakes, by virtue of membership in the WTO, "to accord sympathetic consideration to and afford adequate opportunity for consultation regarding any representations made by another member" [Understanding, Art. 4; Legal Texts, pp. 407-408].
  14. For example, a duopoly for fixed service and/or cellular.
  15. We use the general phrase "national market", for brevity, to encompass all of the four different "modes of supply" defined in the GATS, and explained on pp. ES5-ES6.
  16. Annex on Article II Exemptions (Legal Texts, p. 352); WTO Agreement, Art. IX, § 3, 4 (Legal Texts, pp. 11-12).
  17. The meaning of "reasonable prices" is of course subject to a great deal of debate, and is by now the subject of a large body of experience and analytical expertise: the field is reviewed in Briefing Report No. 4 in this series, Michael Tyler et al, Interconnection: Regulatory Issues (Geneva, ITU, June 1995), chaps. 3-8.
  18. Regulatory regimes of various countries are analyzed and categorized in "Briefing Report No. 1": Michael Tyler, Options for Regulatory Processes and Procedures in Telecommunications (Geneva, ITU, May 1993).
  19. The authors of this report do not accept this last view. As we indicated in Briefing Report No. 2, there are many ways to maintain and pay for universal service obligations other than prohibiting competitive entry. Michael Tyler, Universal Service and Innovation: Fostering Linked Goals through Regulatory Policy (Geneva, ITU, February 1994).
  20. Although national governments and regulators in EU member states do already have such obligations, under EU legislation, in respect of the regulation of EU-based companies.
  21. In GATS terms, this is an example of supply modes 3 or 4 or both.
  22. Of course, NGBT Participants are unlikely to agree to this unless, in their judgement, enough other countries also agree to similar market-opening commitments on the basis of MFN and national treatment.
  23. See op. cit. fn. 18 above.